Group size

Scaling dynamics and network effects in social coordination

December 9, 2011 — January 2, 2022

cooperation
culture
democracy
economics
ethics
extended self
mind
networks
rhetoric
snarks
social graph
sociology
squad
wonk
Figure 1

Mean-field social cognition. The atoms of community governance. How do group dynamics scale with group size?

1 Metis, legibility and groups

TBD - write about how, as we consider successively larger groups, we note that they need to depend more upon legible structures than upon local metis. There is some kind of Pareto front trading off efficiency and scalability of mechanisms.

Alexirpan, in My Soul is Pony-Scarred for Life Because of You writes:

Over the years, I’ve come around to the “relentless march of the normal” theory. Any culture that gets big — any culture at all — cannot grow and stay big without losing its unique charm, because that unique charm can’t survive in a culture that tries to appeal to everyone. …We all wish we could get both the charm and the popularity.

Related: Scene dynamics.

2 Economic scaling effects

TBD. What is commonly called a “network effect” is a posited scaling law of value/cost/whatever with respect to the total number of nodes, i.e. people, in a social network. Archetypal example, Metcalfe’s law:

the value of a telecommunications network is proportional to the square of the number of connected users of the system

There are various reasons to suppose this simplification is brutal, since we suspect strongly that other things are important, the interpretation of the edges and nodes, the network topology (i.e. the edges and how they are arranged), the types of nodes etc.

Classic critique Metcalfe’s Law is Wrong and here are some elaborations Two Powerful Mental Models: Network Effects and Critical Mass, The Dynamics of Network Effects.

But whatever, we can hypothesise that many common types of social network are structured similarly enough that a scaling law would make sense.

If we want to address those details about what actually happens on that network graph and what the “value” of it might be in context, we can keep on adding details until eventually we are considering network economics.

3 The Dunbar number

Figure 2

A popular old saw due to Robin Dunbar, which had a resurgence on the internet a couple of years ago for the most classic of reasons for something to have a resurgence on the internet — it seems to be about the internet.

The original paper regresses mean primate group size against “neocortex ratio” (ratio of neocortex volume to the volume of the rest of the brain) for various species including humans, identifies a goodish fit and posits that neocortex capacity serves a basically social function whose limits are demonstrated by this group size limit. I find this, in broad outline, plausible, that there is a limited budget of time/cognition/spoons available for social coordination, and it certainly raises some interesting research questions.

The next part I am less enthusiastic about. He then goes on to note that it is of course a bit more complex with humans, and suggests a tri-modal distribution of group sizes for humans based upon hunter-gatherer societies (who are the most ‘natural’ groupings.) Specifically, human groups tend to be organised in fluid, nested hierarchical sizes which cluster around group sizes of 30ish, 150ish and 1000ish.

Confidence intervals for the neocortical regression have a factor of 3 margin for error, and the group sizes themselves are highly fiddly to calculate, and hard to disentangle from, e.g. ecological carrying capacity constraints. But it’s a neat idea, eh? Certainly Dunbar has been able to dine out on it for years, which is the hallmark of neatness. Or definition, maybe?

This is a bit too sloppy for actual predictive use. For a start, Dunbar suggests these numbers are good for predicting long-term sustainable group memberships, but that short-term group sizes might be different. Next the magic numbers are all too sloppy to be of actual use. Finally, numbers like this are an invitation to confirmation bias, i.e. if you don’t find Dunbar group sizes, then maybe your definition of “group” is wrong. How often do people have to turn up to count? But even if one does a comprehensive survey of group sizes, what are we identifying? A human cognitive constraint? A constraint on time investment in relationships? Or on task-coordination?

The web-driven resurgence in the idea has been about the discovery of many groups online that happen to fit Dunbar numbers, online communities being fertile ground for group spotting. I still think it is suggestive to see that people are bad at treating 100 people as intimately as they can 3 or four, but if you put it that way, then you are barely saying anything interesting at all.

4 Structuring networks

We would like to design a network to keep coordination costs low. How do we do that?

TBD.

5 Effect upon teamwork

See teamwork.

6 References

Baldassarri, and Grossman. 2013. The Effect of Group Attachment and Social Position on Prosocial Behavior. Evidence from Lab-in-the-Field Experiments.” Edited by Angel Sánchez. PLoS ONE.
Bernhard, Fischbacher, and Fehr. 2006. Parochial altruism in humans.” Nature.
Bowles. 2001. Individual Interactions, Group Conflicts, and the Evolution of Preferences.” Social Dynamics.
Bowles, and Gintis. 2004. The Evolution of Strong Reciprocity: Cooperation in Heterogeneous Populations.” Theoretical Population Biology.
Boyd, and Richerson. 1992. Punishment Allows the Evolution of Cooperation (or Anything Else) in Sizable Groups.” Ethology and Sociobiology.
Bretherton, and Dunbar. 2020. Dunbar’s Number Goes to Church: The Social Brain Hypothesis as a Third Strand in the Study of Church Growth.” Archive for the Psychology of Religion.
Briscoe, Odlyzko, and Tilly. 2006. Metcalfe’s Law Is Wrong.” IEEE Spectrum.
Couzin, Ioannou, Demirel, et al. 2011. Uninformed Individuals Promote Democratic Consensus in Animal Groups.” Science.
Dunbar. 1993. Coevolution of Neocortex Size, Group Size and Language in Humans.” Behavioral and Brain Sciences.
Gintis, Smith, and Bowles. 2001. Costly Signaling and Cooperation.” Journal of Theoretical Biology.
Gould. 2002. The Origins of Status Hierarchies: A Formal Theory and Empirical Test.” American Journal of Sociology.
Hardin. 1971. Collective Action as an Agreeable n-Prisoners’ Dilemma.” Behavioral Science.
Hauert, Monte, Hofbauer, et al. 2002. Volunteering as Red Queen Mechanism for Cooperation in Public Goods Games.” Science.
Henrich, and Boyd. 1998. The Evolution of Conformist Transmission and the Emergence of Between-Group Differences.” Evolution and Human Behavior.
Horst, Kirman, and Teschl. 2007. Changing Identity: The Emergence of Social Groups.” Economics Working Paper 0078.
Klug, and Bagrow. 2016. Understanding the Group Dynamics and Success of Teams.” Royal Society Open Science.
Maner. 2017. Dominance and Prestige: A Tale of Two Hierarchies.” Current Directions in Psychological Science.
Mead, and Maner. 2012. When Me Versus You Becomes Us Versus Them: How Intergroup Competition Shapes Ingroup Psychology.” Social and Personality Psychology Compass.
Moral Sentiments and Material Interests: The Foundations of Cooperation in Economic Life. 2006.
Nowak. 2006. Five Rules for the Evolution of Cooperation.” Science.
Olson. 2009. The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups.
Pavlogiannis, Tkadlec, Chatterjee, et al. 2018. Construction of Arbitrarily Strong Amplifiers of Natural Selection Using Evolutionary Graph Theory.” Communications Biology.
Richerson, Boyd, and Henrich. 2003. “Cultural Evolution of Human Cooperation.” Genetic and Cultural Evolution of Cooperation.