Agent-based models

Science as Grand Theft Auto

July 28, 2011 — April 19, 2023

agents
economics
mind
sociology

…comprise a particular emphasis within the broad field of simulating stuff. An agent-based simulation designed to approximate the behaviour of some real-world system will tend to avoid partial differential equations or fixed-point proofs in favour of, say, breaking down a large system into the component chunks that make it up. If we were looking at a simulation of an economy, an agent-based version might start from the individual humans buying and selling within that economy. Within that simulation, we might be interested in working out, say, ‘given what we know about humans and can simulate, what does that tell us about markets?’ “Bottom-up” modelling would be a more suggestive name.

1 Examples

Figure 1: Nicky Case, Overfishing versus ghost whales
  • Roll your own, code-free using Nicky Case’s Emoji prototype.

    Howdy! 🌻 This (prototype) is a tool that lets you simulate systems of the world. In emoji.

    My hope is that this can help people make more stuff like Parable of the Polygons, interactives that help people understand the complex systems of the world we live in. Also, emoji. In this simulation, you can edit EVERYTHING. Draw on the grid, modify the rules, even change these very words you’re reading! And at the end, you can save and share your creation. That’s the cool thing: there is no difference between playing & making, between reading & writing.

  • or Alex Komorske’s entrant, jkomoros/CASsim: Complex Adaptive Systems Simulator

    CASsim stands for Complex Adaptive Systems simulator. This is a very basic harness and framework to make configurable, interactive agent-based models and then generate animated screenshots of their results.

  • Nobel Laureate Thomas Schelling’s 1969 Racial segregation model based on checkers pieces.

  • As a kind of primordial ancestor, the classic Ising spin glass model

  • A modern example — EpiCast simulates the entire population of the USA, or at least, a lot more detail about them for disease control than I would have suspected to be reasonable.

2 What are they for?

The problem, the basic problem of science, runs something like this — our current models of system \(X\) with parameter set \(P\) are good at approximating some of the observed behaviours of reality for some range of parameters \(p \subset P\), and that range can be fairly easy to find. However, our model does not seem to be able to produce observed behaviour \(b\) for any value of parameters. Let’s remove some of the simplifying assumptions in our model of \(X\) and make it a more complex model, \(X'\) with more parameters \(P'\), and more diverse behaviours. Now it can possibly produce behaviour \(b\) for some values of parameters \(p'\subset P'. But we are no longer assured that we can find the set\)p’ because of, e.g., loss of nice analytic forms for our model, or because of the curse of dimensionality.

Typically agent-based models come out poorly here because they have vastly more parameters to fit and no more data points to fit them to than does anyone else. In macroeconomics, for example, there are a lot more parameters to an economy full of different agents with unique behavioural heuristics and methods of production and technologies, etc., than there are when you assume an equilibrium can be reached by some kind of process of aggregating demand and supply functions. Although you can add more parameters to models based on either set of techniques, or devise hybrid models.

These days we have a lot of compute and a lot of data, at least of some sorts of data, and better fitting algorithms. We can use these to, perhaps, discard some of our simplifying assumptions by producing them as an emergent property of an underlying process, so we have the luxury, perhaps, of using agent models whose behaviour is harder to simplify, and running the model anyway.

Alternatively, even if we can’t ever hope to fit the model to real data, we can still run models that test out various possible sets of assumptions about behaviour in the hope of getting it at least qualitatively right, and congratulate ourselves that we have not only gotten insight, but preserved ourselves from the danger of mistaking our model of reality for reality itself.

Or we might like to use agent-based models because, in some sense, such models are more intuitive than more mathematical abstractions. Moreover, in this case, the intuitive models might give more direct insight into what is happening in a particular situation by letting non-specialists participate more directly. This collaborative option is called companion modelling and it dwells in the dangerous no-man’s-land between science, policy, and community engagement; I, for one, am terrified of that area. I’d much rather analyze a problem from the outside, be annoyed when no one takes my advice, and glean the same sense of righteousness, with much less time and money spent.

Things to be interested in:

  • Agent-based models that include realistic constraints of agent attention and search strategies.
  • Economic models that include not only innovation, but plausible representations of the size of innovation search space and the costs of exploring it. Not necessarily remotely possible.

Now, read:

3 Curiosities

CSIRO ABM used to be a thing.

4 References

Axelrod. 1997a. The Complexity of Cooperation: Agent-Based Models of Competition and Collaboration.
———. 1997b. The Dissemination of Culture: A Model with Local Convergence and Global Polarization.” The Journal of Conflict Resolution.
Bednar, and Page. 2000. “Can Game(s) Theory Explain Culture? The Emergence of Cultural Behavior Within Multiple Games.”
Bianchi, and Squazzoni. 2015. Agent-Based Models in Sociology.” WIREs Computational Statistics.
Bowles. 2004. Microeconomics: Behavior, Institutions, and Evolution.
Bowles, and Gintis. 2004. The Evolution of Strong Reciprocity: Cooperation in Heterogeneous Populations.” Theoretical Population Biology.
Dyer, Cannon, Farmer, et al. 2022. Black-Box Bayesian Inference for Economic Agent-Based Models.” arXiv:2202.00625 [Cs, Econ, Stat].
Epstein. 2001. Learning to Be Thoughtless: Social Norms and Individual Computation.” Computational Economics.
———. 2007. Generative Social Science: Studies in Agent-Based Computational Modeling. Princeton Studies in Complexity.
———. 2009. Modelling to Contain Pandemics.” Nature.
Epstein, Steinbruner, and Parker. 2002. Modeling Civil Violence: An Agent-Based Computational Approach.” Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences.
Gintis. 2007. The Dynamics of General Equilibrium.” The Economic Journal.
Grimm, and Railsback. 2005. Individual-Based Modeling and Ecology: (Princeton Series in Theoretical and Computational Biology).
Grossmann, Feinberg, Parker, et al. 2023. AI and the Transformation of Social Science Research.” Science.
Hailu, and Schilizzi. 2004. Are Auctions More Efficient Than Fixed Price Schemes When Bidders Learn? Australian Journal of Management.
Henke. 2009. How Terrorist Groups Survive: A Dynamic Network Analysis Approach to the Resilience of Terrorist Organizations.” ATZL-SWV.
Hetzer, and Sornette. 2009. Other-Regarding Preferences and Altruistic Punishment: A Darwinian Perspective.” SSRN Scholarly Paper ID 1468517.
Horst, Kirman, and Teschl. 2007. Changing Identity: The Emergence of Social Groups.” Economics Working Paper 0078.
Kirman. 2010. “Learning in Agent Based Models.”
Latek, Axtell, and Kaminski. 2009. “Bounded Rationality via Recursion.” In.
Lorenz. 2010. Heterogeneous Bounds of Confidence: Meet, Discuss and Find Consensus! Complexity.
Lux. 2008. “Applications of Statistical Physics in Finance and Economics.” In Applications of Statistical Physics in Finance and Economics.
Ormerod, and Wiltshire. 2009. ‘Binge’ Drinking in the UK: A Social Network Phenomenon.” Mind & Society.
Pluchino, Rapisarda, and Garofalo. 2010. The Peter Principle Revisited: A Computational Study.” Physica A: Statistical Mechanics and Its Applications.
Riolo, Cohen, and Axelrod. 2001. Evolution of Cooperation Without Reciprocity.” Nature.
Rivkin. 2001. “Reproducing Knowledge: Replication Without Imitation at Moderate Complexity.” Organization Science.
Rosewell, and Ormerod. 2004. How Much Can Firms Know? Computing in Economics and Finance 2004.
Silver, Byrne, and Adler. 2021. Venues and Segregation: A Revised Schelling Model.” PLOS ONE.
Smolin. 2009. “Time and Symmetry in Models of Economic Markets.”
Squazzoni, Jager, and Edmonds. 2014. Social Simulation in the Social Sciences: A Brief Overview.” Social Science Computer Review.
Straatman, White, and Banzhaf. 2008. “An Artificial Chemistry-Based Model of Economies.” Artificial Life.
Tesfatsion, and Judd, eds. 2006. Handbook of Computational Economics, Volume 2: Agent-Based Computational Economics.
Thurner, and Hanel. 2010. “Peer-Review in a World with Rational Scientists: Toward Selection of the Average.”
Walker, and Janssen. 2002. Rangelands, Pastoralists and Governments: Interlinked Systems of People and Nature.” Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences.
Weng, Flammini, Vespignani, et al. 2012. Competition Among Memes in a World with Limited Attention.” Scientific Reports.